European Union

How much could Brexit wipe off UK GDP?

The St George's Cross, European Union and Union flags fly outside a hotel in London, Britain, December 17, 2015. European Union leaders could clinch a deal with British Prime Minister David Cameron in February to prevent the bloc's second largest economy leaving, European Council President Donald Tusk said on Thursday. Cameron is seeking to renegotiate Britain's relationship with the bloc it joined in 1973 ahead of a referendum on membership to be held by the end of 2017. Some EU leaders are wary of agreeing to all of his demands, however, particularly on cutting benefits for EU migrants to Britain.

A meta-analysis assesses the potential economic impact of a vote to leave in the UK's referendum. Image: REUTERS/Luke MacGregor

Berthold Busch
Senior Economist, Cologne Institute for Economic Research
Juergen Matthes
Head of the International Economics and Economic Outlook unit, Cologne Institute for Economic Research
Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how European Union is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

European Union

A plethora of analyses attempt to quantify the economic effects of Brexit (or of EU membership) for the UK. The results are rather confusing – ranging from significant advantages to marked losses. The most pessimistic study concludes that the UK is worse off by about 11.5% of GDP because of EU membership (Congdon 2014, p. 25). The other extreme is covered by studies that estimate the possible benefits of the UK’s membership of the EU to be in the range of 20% (GDP per capita) or more (Henrekson et al. 1997, Badinger 2005, Campos et al. 2015). A range in the order of more than 30 percentage points certainly appears to be quite astounding and calls for a deeper comparative analysis.

We attempt this venture with a thorough meta-analysis (Busch and Matthes 2016). Our study portrays the various economic effects of Brexit qualitatively and provides a systematic overview of the main studies (published as of early April 2016). We distinguish between theory-based, forward-looking (ex ante) studies (many of which, but not all, are based on own models) and backward-looking (ex post) studies. Our comparison shows that the diverging results can be explained by significantly different methods and assumptions, as well as varying coverage of effects.

Only moderate and manageable effects?

Obviously, only studies that include positive and negative effects of Brexit provide a sound basis for summarising conclusions. On the positive side, fiscal savings due to the (partial) elimination of EU contributions and lower economic distortions are relevant because the UK can lower external EU trade barriers and can withdraw from the Common Agricultural Policy in case of Brexit. On the negative side, the losses due to reduced trade integration are augmented by future losses from foregone new EU trade agreements and from foregone reductions of non-tariff barriers in the Internal Market. Our overview portrays the various effects covered (or not covered) by each study. It shows that no forward-looking study covers all relevant aspects at the same time in sufficient detail.

Based on the ex ante model-based studies considered relatively reliable and comprehensive,[1] a certain consensus seems to have emerged.

First, the disadvantages from lower economic integration appear to outweigh the economic advantages. However, overall, several reviews come to similar (mainstream) conclusions that the net economic effects of Brexit should lie in the lower single digit range between 1% and mostly significantly below 5% of GDP in the longer term (e.g. CEBR 2015, p. 28, CBI 2013, p. 79). Thus, the economic effects of Brexit seem manageable and the decision to leave the EU appears to be mainly a political consideration about sovereignty and self-determination.

Serious doubts about the mainstream conclusion

However, we raise serious doubts about this mainstream conclusion. In fact, important shortcomings of the mainstream methods are likely to conceal significantly higher risks. Even the more reliable forward-looking, model-based studies are unable to cover all relevant channels by which economic integration raises welfare.

Figures 1 to 3 provide an overview of the effects which are hardly covered: positive static and dynamic trade effects on welfare and growth, as well as additional non-trade effects of economic integration. Particularly, positive effects from higher competition on innovation and on firm selection, which are induced by more trade and FDI, are hardly covered. We take stock of the substantial theoretic and empirical support for these additional welfare and growth effects thoroughly. In doing so, we point out, however, that the available empirical evidence concerns only the individual effects and is hardly focused on European integration or the case of Brexit.

The general problem for economists lies in the fact that there is no universally accepted theory-based ex ante estimation method available to integrate all of these specific effects in a comprehensive way. Going beyond the available forward-looking methods towards ex post analyses implies entering somewhat less solid ground. We venture on this avenue and present several backward-looking studies that use existing data. These studies attempt to quantify comprehensive welfare effects of EU integration or Brexit, but are able to do so only in an implicit and less theoretically explicit way. All of these attempts can be criticised to some extent, because it is notoriously difficult to ascribe welfare effects to EU integration as many other factors influence welfare at the same time. However, the overall take on backward-looking studies suggests that Brexit could cause a significantly worse economic impact in a more pessimistic scenario than the mainstream conclusions indicate.

Figure 1. Selected static effects of trade on welfare levels

Selected static effects of trade on welfare levels.
Image: VOX EU

Notes: Green arrow: effect covered in most ex ante CGE and NQTM trade models (not in non-trade CGE models for UK); dotted green arrow: effect covered in at least one, but only a few ex ante models; these models only cover selected effects; black arrow: effect not covered in ex ante models.
Source: Authors’ own design.

Figure 2. Selected dynamic effects of trade on economic growth

 Selected dynamic effects of trade on economic growth
Image: VOX EU

Notes: Dotted green arrow: effect covered in at least one, but only a few ex ante models; these models only cover selected effects; black arrow: effect not covered in ex ante models.
Source: Authors’ own design.

Figure 3. Selected effects on non-trade integration

 Selected effects on non-trade integration
Image: VOX EU

Notes: Dotted green arrow: effect covered in at least one, but only a few ex ante models; these models only cover selected effects; black arrow: effect not covered in ex ante models.
Source: Authors’ own design.

Results from backward-looking studies

Sound evidence exists that theoretical forward-looking trade models tend to underestimate the trade effects of economic integration. In fact, ex post studies tend to find significantly larger trade effects of trade agreements than ex ante models, such as CGE models (Rosa and Gilbert 2005, Baier et al. 2008, Pelkmans et al. 2014). Recent methodological developments tend to increase this divergence. A new strand of the literature argues that traditional gravity models – the workhorse for ex post analysis of trade agreements – also tend to underestimate trade outcomes (Baier and Bergstrand 2007, Egger et al. 2011). Based on a more modern gravity approach, Baier et al. (2008) estimate that membership of the EU (and of its institutional predecessors) has raised trade between members by between 100% and 125% over a 15-year period alone.

Based on these insights, we describe three strands of backward-looking studies that attempt to quantify additional welfare, income and growth effects in a more encompassing (but necessarily only implicit) way (Busch and Matthes 2016).

-Using recent forecasts for the negative effects of Brexit on bilateral trade between the UK and the EU, the induced income decline can be quantified in a tentative way. Based on a generaltrade-income-relationshipcalculated by recent thorough studies, three studies estimate that UK incomes could possibly decline by around 10% or more in a more pessimistic scenario (Ottaviano et al. 2014, Aichele and Felbermayr 2015, Crafts 2015). An important shortcoming of these attempts lies in the fact that the trade-income relationship could not be tailored specifically to the UK.

-Several studies employ regression analyses(Henrekson et al. 1997, Badinger 2005, Crespo Cuaresma et al. 2008). Even though the results differ in their details, these studies identify sizeable effects of EU membership on the level of GDP in the long term – mostly in the range of 20% or more. However, some uncertainties remain, as the results are in part not completely robust and as growth regressions are notoriously difficult to make watertight.

-Campos et al. (2014, 2015) apply a relatively new synthetic counterfactual method (SCM) which was developed by Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003). Mimicking the approach of clinical studies, the authors construct an artificial synthetic control group by selecting countries with similar economic performance to the UK during a longer time beforeEU accession in 1973 (pre-treatment period). The effect of EU membership (treatment) can be deduced from the difference between the economic outcome for the UK and that for the control group. Campos et al. (2015) estimate that in the long run (between EU accession by the UK up to 2008), real GDP per capita in the UK is nearly 24% higher than in the synthetic control group. However, this result is not very robust. Focusing on the findings of various robustness checks on productivity increases over a ten-year horizon, the respective results lie in the higher single digit range (up to 10%). This is still a substantial result, particularly when taking into consideration that benefits might increase further over time.

Conclusion

Figure 4 provides an overview of our approach, which can be summarised as follows:

The forward-looking, mainstream model-based studies are unable to capture many additional effects of economic integration on welfare and growth.

Therefore, the mainstream results which conclude that Brexit would cause only moderate economic damage should be taken with caution.

Higher risks appear likely when the specific additional welfare and growth effects are analysed.

The same is true when the fact that backward-looking studies find significantly larger trade effects of economic integration agreements than forward-looking models is taken into account.

Therefore, backward-looking studies which derive welfare effects should not be neglected in building an opinion on the possible economic outcome of Brexit.

While not completely robust, they provide important indications that the economic loss to the UK could be significantly larger than in the low single digit range.

This would be particularly relevant in case the political striving for regaining regulatory sovereignty in the UK prevails and, as a result, the future degree of economic integration between the UK and the EU deteriorates significantly.

In this more pessimistic scenario, our study warns of the risk that GDP losses to the UK in the broad range of 10% or more cannot be ruled out in the long run in case of Brexit.

Figure 4. Approach of the meta study of existing studies on Brexit

Confusing results of Brexit studies
Image: VOX EU

References

Abadie, A. and J. Gardeazabal (2003), “The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country”, American Economic Review 93(1), pp. 113–132.

Aichele, R. and G. Felbermayr (2015), Kosten und Nutzen eines Austritts des Vereinigten Königreichs aus der Europäischen Union, April, Munich.

Badinger, H. (2005), “Growth Effects of Economic Integration: Evidence from the EU Member States”, Review of World Economics 141, pp. 50–78.

Baier, S. L. and J. H. Bergstrand (2007), “Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade?”, Journal of International Economics 71(1), pp. 72–95.

Baier, S. L., J. H. Bergstrand, P. Egger and P. A. McLaughlin (2008), “Do Economic Integration Agreements Actually Work? Issues in Understanding the Causes and Consequences of the Growth of Regionalism”, The World Economy 31(4), pp. 461−497

Booth, S. et al. (2015), What if …? The consequences, challenges and opportunities facing Britain outside the EU, Open Europe Report, No. 3, London

Campos, N. F., F. Coricelli and L. Moretti (2014), “Economic Growth and Political Integration: Estimating the Benefits from Membership in the EU Using the Synthetic Counterfactuals Method”, IZA Discussion paper, No. 8162, Bonn

Campos, N. F., F. Coricelli and L. Moretti (2015), “Deep Integration and Economic Growth: Counterfactual Evidence from Europe”, mimeo, Brunel University

Confederation of British Industries (CBI) (2013) Our Global Future, The Business Vision for a Reformed EU.

Centre for Economic and Business Research (CEBR) (2015), The impact of the UK being in the Single Market, Report for Britain Stronger in Europe, October,

Congdon, T. (2014), “How much does the EU cost Britain?”, UKIP, Dagenham

Crafts, N. (2015), “West European Economic Integration since 1950: Implications for Trade and Income”, University of Warwick mimeo.

Crespo Cuaresma, J., D. Ritzberger-Grünwald and M. A. Silgoner (2008), “Growth, Convergence and EU Membership”, Applied Economics 40(5), pp. 643–656

Dhingra, S., G. Ottaviano, T. Sampson and J. van Reenen (2016), “The consequences of Brexit for UK trade and living standards”, CEP, London.

Egger, P., M. Larch, K. E. Staub and R. Winkelmann (2011), “The Trade Effects of Endogenous Preferential Trade Agreements”, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3(3), pp. 113–143

Henrekson, M., J. Torstensson and R. Torstensson (1997), “Growth Effects of European Integration”, European Economic Review 41, pp. 1537-1557

Ottaviano, G., J. P. Pessoa, T. Sampson and J. van Reenen (2014), “The costs and benefits of leaving the EU”, CFS Working Paper, No. 472, Frankfurt am Main

Oxford Economics (2016), Assessing the economic implications of Brexit, Executive Summary, London

Pain, N. and G. Young (2004), The macroeconomic impact of UK withdrawal from the EU, National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London

Pelkmans, J., A. Lejour, L. Schrefler, F. Mustilli and J. Timini (2014), “The Impact of TTIP: The underlying economic model and comparisons”, CEPS Special Report, No. 93, Brussels

De Rosa, D. A. and J. P. Gilbert (2005), “Predicting Trade Expansion under FTAs and Multilateral Agreements”, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Working Paper, No. 05-13

Endnotes

[1] See e.g. Ottaviano et al. 2014, Booth et al. 2015, Aichele and Felbermayr 2015, Dhingra et al. 2016 for CGE trade models; and Pain and Young 2004, PwC 2016, Oxford Economics 2016 for general CGE macroeconomic models.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

1:42

This EU law will make companies check their supply chains for forced labour

Kimberley Botwright and Spencer Feingold

March 27, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum