Economic Progress

An economic impact of migration you might not have considered

People cross a street in Mong Kok district in Hong Kong, October 4, 2011. Mong Kok has the highest population density in the world, with 130,000 in one square kilometre. The world's population will reach seven billion on 31 October 2011, according to projections by the United Nations, which says this global milestone presents both an opportunity and a challenge for the planet. While more people are living longer and healthier lives, says the U.N., gaps between rich and poor are widening and more people than ever are vulnerable to food insecurity and water shortages.   Picture taken October 4, 2011.   REUTERS/Bobby Yip   (CHINA - Tags: SOCIETY) - RTR2SQJP

Foreign direct investment is found to follow the paths of historical migrants. Image: REUTERS/Bobby Yip

Konrad Buchardi
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Economic Progress?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Economic Progress is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Economic Progress

Over the past decades, international migrations have reached unprecedented levels, shaping an increasingly ethnically diverse and socially connected world. The economic consequences of these migrations are at the heart of fierce political debates on immigration policy, yet our understanding of the economic effects of migrations remains incomplete. At the same time, local policymakers see attracting and retaining foreign direct investment (FDI) as a major goal, and technology transfers through FDI are both a conduit for technological progress abroad and a source of revenue for US firms (Holmes et al. 2015, McGrattan and Prescott 2010). In this column, we show that immigration and FDI are intimately related – the ethnic diversity created by migrations reaching back more than a century has a large positive causal effect on the ability of US firms to engage in FDI with the historical migrants' countries of origin.

Correlation versus causation

Evaluating the causal impact of migrations on FDI is tricky – many unobserved factors may simultaneously affect migrations, ancestry, and FDI, creating a spurious correlation between them. For example, migrants from Sweden may have historically settled in Minneapolis because it is climatically similar to their origin country, and these climatic similarities may also drive trade, business opportunities, and investments in Sweden today. Does Minneapolis receive Swedish investments today because of the weather or because of the presence of descendants of Swedish origin?

In a recent paper, we distinguish causation from correlation using an approach that is best explained by the examples of migrations from Germany and Italy (Burchardi et al. 2016). In particular, German migrations to the US peaked at the end of the 19th century when the Midwest was booming and attracting large numbers of migrants. We observe a relatively large population with German ancestry in the Midwest today. Italian migrations peaked a few decades later, at the beginning of the 20th century when the West was attracting large numbers of migrants. We observe a relatively large population with Italian ancestry in the West today.

We use this interaction of time-series variation in the relative attractiveness of different destinations within the US with the staggered arrival of migrants from different origins to instrument for the present-day distribution of ancestries. One may think of migrations from a given origin country to a given US destination county in decade as depending on the total number of migrants arriving in the US from that origin (a push factor) and the relative popularity of the destination among migrants arriving at the time (a pull factor). The number of residents in a given US destination today who are descendants of migrants from a given origin should then depend on interactions of the sequence of pull and push factors going all the way back to the 19th century.

To construct valid instruments from this sequence of interactions, we isolate variation in the pull and push factors that is independent of any unobservables that may make a given destination within the US differentially more attractive for both settlement and FDI from a given origin country. To that end, we leave out the migrants’ continent of origin when calculating the share of migrants choosing a given destination (the pull factor), and leave out the states surrounding a destination when calculating the push factor for a given destination. For example, we predict the number of Swedes that settle in Minneapolis in 1920 with the interaction of the share of non-European migrants arriving at the time that settle in Minneapolis and the number of Swedes arriving in the US at the same time that do not settle in the Midwest.

The effect of ancestry on FDI

Using this approach, we document that FDI follows the paths of historical migrants as much as it follows differences in productivity, tax rates, education, and other conventional determinants of economic competitiveness – for the average US county, doubling the number of individuals with ancestry from a given origin country increases by 4 percentage points the probability that at least one firm from this US county engages in FDI with that origin country, and increases by 29% the number of local jobs at subsidiaries of firms headquartered in that origin country. As an example, Figure 1 shows the relationship between the number of foreign subsidiaries based in Cook County, Illinois, and the predicted number of residents with ancestry from that foreign country.

Figure 1. Foreign subsidiaries by ancestry in Cook Country, IL

Foreign subsidiaries by ancestry in Cook Country, IL
Image: Vox EU

Mechanism

Theory suggests three potential mechanisms that could be driving these causal effects of ancestry on FDI. The presence of individuals with a given foreign ancestry may generate a comparative advantage for local firms:

- By facilitating the flow of information

- By providing social capital to enforce contracts where courts do not work well; or

- Because the descendants of migrants and the present-day population of origin countries may have shared tastes for consumption goods.

We find an array of evidence most consistent with the first channel. The effect of ancestry on FDI is largest for countries that have better (rather than worse) rule of law. Similarly, the effect is larger for intermediate goods than for consumption goods (weighing against the preference-based channel). We also find that the effect of ancestry on FDI is largest for relationships that we might consider to be most associated with asymmetric information – it is largest for countries that are furthest away geographically and in sectors that may be associated with a higher degree of information asymmetry (manufacturing versus natural resources). In addition, the effect of ancestry on FDI is highly concave, as one might expect in a model where information asymmetry is the main friction – the first few descendants from a given origin have a significantly higher marginal impact; similarly, there are negative spillovers where the marginal impact of a group of descendants of, for example, Swedish ancestry in a given county falls with the size of the Swedish population in the state, and with the size of individuals of ancestry from neighbouring countries (Chaney 2014, Arkolakis 2010).

We also find that the effect of ancestry on FDI is very long-lasting – migrations ranging all the way back to 1880 have a significant effect on the patterns of FDI that exist today. Interestingly, the effect of immigration on FDI is significantly smaller for first-generation immigrants (Borjas 2006).

An example: The effect of Chinese exclusion

To illustrate the quantitative implications of our results, we calculate the effect of Chinese exclusion – the effective ban on Chinese immigration between 1882 and 1965. Absent this ban, we predict the fraction of counties in the Northeast with FDI links to China would have increased substantially (doubled in New York State, for example; see Figure 2).

Figure 2. FDI links with China in the absence of Chinese exclusion

 FDI links with China in the absence of Chinese exclusion
Image: Vox EU

References

Arkolakis, C (2010) "Market penetration costs and the new consumer margin in international trade", Journal of Political Economy, 118(5): 1151-99.

Borjas, G J (2006) “Making it in America: Social mobility in the immigrant population”, NBER, Working Paper 12088.

Burchardi, K B and T A Hassan (2013) “The economic impact of social ties: Evidence from German reunification”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128: 1219-1271.

Burchardi, K B, T Chaney and T A Hassan (2016) “Migrants, ancestors, and foreign investments”, NBER, Working Paper 21847.

Chaney, T (2014) "The network structure of international trade", American Economic Review,104(11): 3600-34.

Chaney, T (2016) “Networks in international trade”, in Y Bramoulle, A Galleoti and B Rogers (eds),Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Networks, Oxford University Press.

Fuchs-Schuendeln, N and T A Hassan (2015) “Natural experiments in macroeconomics”, NBER, Working Paper 21228.

Holmes, T J, E R McGrattan and E C Prescott (2015) “Quid pro quo: Technology capital transfers for market access in China", The Review of Economic Studies, 82: 1154-1193.

McGrattan, E R and E C Prescott (2010) “Technology capital and the US current account", American Economic Review, 100: 1493-1522.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

IMF says global economy 'remains remarkably resilient', and other economics news

Joe Myers

April 19, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum