Advanced Manufacturing

Productivity, innovation and friction in the economy

Thongdee Saenghow, a 62-year-old production supervisor, works at a rice vermicelli factory outside Bangkok, Thailand, February 5, 2016. The World Bank estimates the working-age population will shrink by 11 percent by 2040, the fastest contraction among Southeast Asia's developing countries. Thailand's stage of economic development, the rising cost of living and education, and a population waiting longer to get married are among the reasons it is ageing more quickly than its neighbours. An effective contraception programme in the 1970s also played a part, said Sutayut Osornprasop, a human development specialist at the World Bank in Thailand. Picture taken February 5, 2016. REUTERS/Jorge Silva  - RTX269TE

This productivity dispersion—in combination with declining growth rates—points toward explanations of the slowdown that involve a breakdown in the diffusion of productivity among firms. Image: REUTERS/Jorge Silva

Nick Bunker
Policy Analyst, Washington Center for Equitable Growth
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Advanced Manufacturing?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Advanced Manufacturing is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Advanced Manufacturing

By now, the slowdown in productivity growth in the United States and other high-income countries is a well-known and much lamented trend. A slightly less appreciated aspect of productivity growth is that the slowdown has been accompanied by an increase in dispersion, or inequality, of labor productivity across firms. This trend is not restricted to the U.S. economy. The Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development has identified it as a problem for most high-income economies. This productivity dispersion—in combination with declining growth rates—points toward explanations of the slowdown that involve a breakdown in the diffusion of productivity among firms.

In a new paper for a National Bureau of Economic Research conference, four economists—Lucia Foster and Cheryl Grim of the U.S. Census Bureau and John Haltiwanger and Zoltan Wolf of the University of Maryland—look at what happens to productivity after new firms enter a market due to a new innovation. The authors look at data on productivity that covers the entire U.S. economy, not just the manufacturing sector, which many studies of productivity focus on.

Image: Foster Grim Haltiwanger Wolf 2017

In trying to understand the relationship between innovation and productivity, the authors use a model that examines when an innovation occurs that in turn causes a person (or persons) to start a new business. The new company enters an industry, and the innovation gets spread around. Other new firms enter, and older firms try to adapt their business in light of the new innovation. The result is a rise in the dispersion of productivity across the industry. But then, resources start flowing toward the most productive firms, which increases productivity growth.

The analysis in the paper finds that this description of productivity growth holds up when examining the data from the productivity increases of the late 1990s. The entry of new firms with new innovations increased, resulting in increased productivity dispersion in the short term, followed by higher productivity growth three to four years after the increased entry. But the description seems to break down during the productivity slowdown of the 2000s. The entry of new firms into the economy declined, yet productivity inequality increased while growth slowed. The end result today is that high-productivity firms exist next to low-productivity firms. We might expect that the new innovation would spread throughout the economy, but something has stopped that transmission from happening.

The authors note this combination of trends points toward frictions in the economy—in the form of barriers to entry or a lack of responsiveness to productivity shocks—due to resources not necessarily flowing to the more productive firms. These frictions, especially when it comes to employment, may sound similar to readers of studies about rising inequality between firms. As James Pethokoukis at the American Enterprise Institute points out, the increased sorting of firms into high-productivity and low-productivity groups is also about income inequality. Economic analysis that seeks to explain both why productivity isn’t diffusing and why interfirm income inequality—higher wages and high productivity growth among some firms and low-wage growth amid low productivity growth among others—is rising are ones that policymakers should pay more attention to.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Advanced ManufacturingEconomic Progress
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

2:06

‘Microfactories’ could be the future of manufacturing

Stephanie Wright, Memia Fendri and Kyle Winters

February 13, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum