Economic Progress

Have economists solved this puzzle from the Great Recession?

Pedestrians are reflected on a graph display showing the exchange rate between Japanese yen and Euro outside of a brokerage in Tokyo August 10, 2010. The Bank of Japan on Tuesday held off on new policy steps to combat a stronger yen, saving its limited firepower in case the currency's rise accelerates and threatens the fragile economic recovery. REUTERS/Kim Kyung-Hoon (JAPAN - Tags: BUSINESS) - GM1E68A13FQ01

A puzzle left since the Great Recession. Image: REUTERS/Kim Kyung-Hoon (JAPAN - Tags: BUSINESS) - GM1E68A13FQ01

Jesper Lindé
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Economic Progress?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Economic Progress is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Economic Progress

The Great Recession has left macroeconomists with many puzzles. One such puzzle is the alleged breakdown of the relationship between inflation and the output gap – also known as the Phillips curve.

There are two main arguments underlying the hypothesis of a breakdown of the Phillips curve.

The first is the ‘missing deflation puzzle’. The Great Recession generated an extraordinary decline in US GDP of about 10% relative to its pre-crisis trend, while inflation dropped only by about 1.5% (see Figure 1).1 The modest decline in inflation was surprising to many macroeconomists. For instance, New York Fed President John C. Williams (2010: 8) wrote: “The surprise [about inflation] is that it's fallen so little, given the depth and duration of the recent downturn. Based on the experience of past severe recessions, I would have expected inflation to fall by twice as much as it has.”

Figure 1 Log US real GDP per capita and US core inflation

The second argument is the absence of upward pressure on price and wage inflation during the recovery from the Great Recession, sometimes referred to as the ‘missing inflation puzzle’. Standard price and wage Phillips curves imply that wage and price inflation should increase noticeably when the economy recovers from the recession.

The alleged breakdown of the Phillips curve – i.e. its inability to account for the missing deflation and inflation – has left monetary policy researchers and central bank economists wondering if we need to develop completely new models for price and wage determination. Leading policy institutions including the IMF and central banks have devoted considerable resources to understanding the reasons underlying below-target core inflation rates, as well as to crafting appropriate policy responses.2

However, developing completely new models of price and wage determination does not seem to be necessary. In our ongoing research (Lindé and Trabandt 2019), we show that a relatively small alteration of the standard New Keynesian model combined with using the nonlinear solution instead of the linearised is sufficient to resolve both puzzles.

First, we argue that it is key to introduce real rigidities in price setting and wage setting. To do so, we use the Kimball (1995) aggregator instead of the standard Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) aggregator. The Kimball aggregator ‘bends’ the demand curve of firms and thereby introduces additional strategic complementarities in the price and wage setting. More strategic complementarity lowers the sensitivity of prices and wages to slack in goods and labour markets in a recession.

As such, the Kimball aggregator is commonly used in New Keynesian models (e.g. Smets and Wouters 2007) as it allows to simultaneously account for the macroeconomic evidence of a low Phillips curve slope and the microeconomic evidence of frequent price changes. However, although the introduction of real rigidities is necessary in this regard, it is not sufficient to explain the movements in aggregate quantities and prices observed during the Great Recession and the subsequent recovery.

We show that linearising all equilibrium equations of the underlying nonlinear model around the steady state, except for the lower bound constraint on the nominal interest rate, introduces large approximation errors when large adverse shocks hit the economy – as was the case during the Great Recession. Therefore, we argue that one ought to use the nonlinear solution to understand the output-inflation dynamics during the Great Recession. We show that the nonlinearity implied by the Kimball aggregator is a key model feature that accounts for the differences between the linearised and nonlinear model solutions: it is crucial to resolving the missing deflation and inflation puzzles.

In a nutshell, our model implies nonlinear price and wage Phillips curves – i.e. nonlinear relationships between price and wage inflation and the output gap (see Figures 2 and 3).3 The slopes of our price and wage Phillips curves are notably flatter in recessions than in booms. In other words, our Phillips curves have a ‘banana’ or ‘boomerang’ shape as in the seminal paper by Phillips (1958). Consequently, and consistent with the data, our nonlinear model implies that inflation falls relatively little in deep recessions. By contrast, the linearised model erroneously predicts a much larger fall in inflation by extrapolating local decision rules around the steady state to deep recessions far away from the steady state.

Figure 2 Price Phillips curves with nonlinear versus linearised model
Figure 3 Wage Phillips curves with nonlinear versus linearised model

Our research is also useful for understanding the absence of upward pressure of price and wage inflation during the recovery from the Great Recession – i.e. the ‘missing inflation puzzle’. The banana-shaped Phillips curves imply that price and wage inflation remain subdued until the level of economic activity has recovered sufficiently relative to its potential. Put differently, even though economic growth may resume after a deep recession, price and wage inflation will only increase modestly until economic slack has subsided sufficiently.

Have you read?

Therefore, our model not only resolves the missing deflation puzzle, it also offers an explanation for the missing inflation puzzle. According to our model, subdued price and wage inflationary pressures as observed during the recovery from the Great Recession are indicative of substantial economic slack, consistent with Figure 1 which shows that post-crisis GDP has not nearly caught up with the level implied by its pre-crisis trend.4

All told, our nonlinear model allows us to simultaneously explain the quantitative inflation performance prior to the Great Recession, the missing deflation during the Great Recession, as well as the missing inflation in recent years. Our results caution against the common practice of using linearised models to study inflation and output dynamics when the economy is exposed to large shocks.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Economic ProgressGeo-economicsFinancial and Monetary Systems
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

IMF says global economy 'remains remarkably resilient', and other economics news

Joe Myers

April 19, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum