Economic Progress

Why happier workers matter more than you think

Alex Edmans
Professor of Finance, London Business School
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Economic Progress?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Economic Progress is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Economic Progress

Does corporate social responsibility improve the value of a company? When making decisions, should companies only care about shareholders or should they take other stakeholders (e.g. employees, customers, the environment) into account? This is a decades-old debate, but despite many cogent views on both sides, there’s surprisingly little hard evidence.

In 1970, Milton Friedman famously wrote that “the social responsibility of business is to increase its profits”. This view isn’t as hard-hearted as it may sound. Friedman argued that a company can only increase its profits by taking other stakeholders into account – producing high-quality products, treating its employees fairly and having a good environmental reputation. Under this view, firms should focus exclusively on profits, and everything else will fall into place. Considering other stakeholders beyond the profit implication is at the expense of shareholders: a dollar spent on reducing pollution (beyond the level that will avoid an environmental lawsuit) is a dollar that cannot be paid as dividends.

However, advocates of corporate social responsibility (CSR) argue that the Friedman view only holds in theory. In practice, it’s extremely difficult to quantify the profit implications of most socially responsible actions. A company could decide whether to grant an employee compassionate leave by trying to calculate the potential loss in morale and productivity if the leave was withheld, but these consequences are very hard to quantify. The CSR approach would be to grant the leave simply because it’s the right thing to do – because the goal of the company isn’t only to maximize profits, but to treat stakeholders with compassion. Treating employees fairly will eventually manifest in greater staff retention and future productivity. However, these long-run effects are difficult to quantify, so a company focused exclusively on profits will not invest in its stakeholders.

Whether CSR improves firm value has been studied extensively by management scholars. Most studies find a positive correlation between CSR and measures of corporate performance, such as profits. However, correlation doesn’t imply causation. It may not be that CSR causes a firm to perform better, but instead that firm performance causes CSR – only firms that are performing well can afford to spend money on its other stakeholders. In addition, some studies consider only one industry, or a short time period, and so are hard to generalize.

A new approach

I decided to tackle this long-standing management question using a methodology from a different field – finance. This approach involves linking CSR not to profits, but to future stock returns, which reduces reverse causality concerns. If it was high profits that caused CSR, then the high profits would mean the company’s stock price would already be high today, and so we shouldn’t expect higher stock returns in the future.

The next decision is how to measure CSR. The main challenge is that CSR is extremely difficult to measure objectively, as it’s intangible. Tangible measures do exist. For example, one could measure workplace diversity by whether there’s a minority on the board. However, tangible measures are relatively superficial and thus easy to manipulate. A company that cared little about workplace diversity, for instance, could put a token minority on the board to “check the box”. A separate challenge is that CSR comprises many different dimensions – responsibility to employees, customers, the environment, etc – and it’s unclear how to weight these different constituencies.

I thus focused on one particular dimension of social responsibility – employee satisfaction. I chose this dimension because a very thorough measure of it exists. Since 1984, there has been a list of the “100 Best Companies to Work for in America”. This list is compiled by surveying the employees themselves – it’s the ultimate in fundamental, grassroots analysis. Two hundred and fifty employees are randomly selected in a firm and asked 57 questions on various aspects of employee satisfaction (credibility, respect, fairness, pride/camaraderie), which had been developed through extensive discussions with managers, employees and workplace experts. As a result, it’s arguably the most respected measure of employee satisfaction. Equally importantly, it has been available since 1984, and thus I have a long time series, which comprises both recessions and booms.

The first list came out in a book in March 1984, then another book in February 1993, and then in the January edition of Fortune magazine every year from 1998. My methodology involves buying a the Best Companies in April 1984, rebalancing the portfolio in March 1993 to take the new list into account, and then rebalancing it every February from 1998. The one month delay is because I wish to test not only that employee satisfaction improves firm value, but also whether the market recognizes this link. Even if employee satisfaction improves firm value, my strategy should earn no returns if the market recognizes this link. As soon as a company appears in the Best Companies list, its stock price should go up, so I shouldn’t be able to generate returns by buying it one month too late.

I compare the returns of the Best Companies not only to the overall market, but also to companies in the same industry. For example, Google is frequently in the Best Companies list, but its high returns could be due to the tech industry doing well, rather than its employee satisfaction. I also compare each company to peer firms with similar characteristics (e.g. size, dividend yield, recent performance, valuation ratios). In short, I try to control for as much as possible, to isolate the effect of employee satisfaction. I also remove the effect of outliers, to ensure that any superior performance of the Best Companies isn’t due to a few star performers such as Google.

I find that the Best Companies beat the market by 2-3% a year, over a 26-year period from 1984-2009. This outperformance is highly statistically significant, and also economically meaningful – a fund manager who beats the market by 1% a year for five years is considered to be skilled. Moreover, the performance is based on a very simple trading strategy using public information on large firms.

The results have three main implications. First, they suggest that employee satisfaction is beneficial for firm value. While it may seem natural that companies should do better if their workers are happier, this is far from obvious. Indeed, the 20th-century way of managing workers is to view them as any other input – just as managers shouldn’t overpay for or under-use raw materials, they shouldn’t do so with workers. High worker satisfaction may be a sign that workers are overpaid or underworked. However, the world is different nowadays. Human capital is the main asset in many firms, and employee welfare can improve productivity, retention and recruitment.

Second, even though employee satisfaction may be beneficial in the modern firm, the market doesn’t recognize this link. Even though I wait a month before forming my portfolios, the strategy generates superior returns. Similarly, the Best Companies typically report earnings that beat analyst expectations – analysts aren’t aware of the benefits of worker welfare. Indeed, I show that it takes four to five years before the market fully incorporates the value of employee satisfaction. This may be because traditional methods of valuing companies are based on the 20th-century company, and emphasize tangible factors such as short-term profits. This result has broader implications for firms’ incentives to invest for the long run. If investors continue to value companies based on short-term profit, then managers will pursue short-term profit rather than long-run growth.

Third, socially responsible investing (SRI) – incorporating social considerations into portfolio choice – can add value. The traditional view is that SRI is costly to investment performance, as it involves screening out good investments and screening in bad ones. However, the Best Companies strategy generates high returns while supporting companies that treat employees responsibly: investors can do well and do good. This result is a consequence of the first two implications – employee satisfaction is beneficial (the first implication) but the market doesn’t recognize this (the second implication).

In conclusion, it’s worth highlighting some caveats to my study. First, I’ve only shown a link between stock returns and employee satisfaction, and not other dimensions of CSR. Further research must be done to study whether there’s any link with environmental protection, animal rights, etc. However, since the traditional view is that no dimension of CSR should add value, the results are an important first step towards demonstrating the benefits of CSR more broadly. Second, while I control for many observable factors (industry performance, firm size, dividend yield, etc), I can’t rule out the possibility that an unobserved variable (e.g. good management) causes both employee satisfaction and superior returns. If so, my first implication is no longer causal; improving employee satisfaction (without changing management) won’t improve stock returns. However, the other two implications remain. It remains the case that the stock market misvalues intangibles – just that the intangible being misvalued is good management rather than employee satisfaction. It also remains the case that a socially responsible investor could have bought companies that treat their employees well and earned superior returns.

Author: Alex Edmans is Professor of Finance at London Business School, on leave from the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.

Image: A trader smiles on the floor of the New York Stock Exchange March 23, 2009. REUTERS/Shannon Stapleton

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

The latest from the IMF on the global economy, and other economics stories to read

Joe Myers

April 12, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum