Financial and Monetary Systems

A simple way to encourage saving among the poor

Lore Vandewalle
Assistant professor, Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Financial and Monetary Systems?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Financial and Monetary Systems is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Financial and Monetary Systems

Recent studies in development economics have underlined the disappointing results of microcredit programmes.1 The focus has now shifted towards other financial products, such as savings. The substantial demand for savings among the poor has been reflected in their willingness to invest in risky assets, such as jewellery, animals, money under the mattress, and different forms of informal savings arrangements. Therefore, it is important to provide poor households access to products of higher quality, such as bank accounts.

Financial inclusion, a policy priority

Several governments made financial inclusion a policy priority, which led to a rapid increase in bank account penetration in developing countries. Among others, the government of South Africa launched the Mzansi initiative in 2004, the Colombian government created Banca de las Oportunidades in 2006, and the Indian government announced Pradhan mantri Mantri Jan-Dhan Yojana in 2014.2,3 Thanks to the latter scheme, almost 137 million accounts were opened over the past 8 months. It is now estimated that 99% of the households have access to a bank account in India. However, 67.3% of those accounts are dormant.4 These figures are in line with what researchers, investigating the impact of providing formal bank accounts to the poor observed (Ashraf et al. 2006, 2010, Dupas and Robinson 2013a, b). These papers show large take-up rates, but a rather low usage. For instance, Dupas and Robinson (2013a) offered bank accounts to Kenyan micro-entrepreneurs. While 87% took up the account, only 41% made at least one transaction within the first six months. In a similar experiment, Dupas et al. (2012) find a 62% take-up rate, but only an 18% usage rate, even when leniently defining active usage as making at least two deposits a year. Karlan et al. (2014) emphasise that the gap between take-up and usage of formal bank accounts remains to be explained.

How to increase account use?

As for other savings products, bank account use requires an active decision to save (deposit), and therefore some self-control. This might be an important barrier. In high-income countries, products such as automatic transfers have been designed that overcome the need of an active savings decision. For example, when employees faced an automatic enrolment option to 401(k) savings plans in the US, both the participation and the savings rates were higher (Madrian and Shea 2001). In developing economies where most economic transactions are settled in cash, direct transfers on a bank account could bring about similar results. When paid on the account, the money is saved by default, while – as long as payments are done in cash – the money is ready to be spent. We tested this hypothesis in rural India by estimating how changes in the payment method affect consumption and savings (Somville and Vandewalle 2015).

Moving from cash to account based payments triggers savings

We collaborated with Basix Sub-K, an NGO providing banking services on behalf of a bank. They select and train one shop owner per village to become the local banker. Villagers can go to the banker to open a bank account, deposit, withdraw, make transfers, or check their balance.

We sampled 442 villagers in 17 villages in Chhattisgarh. All of them either had an account, or were assisted in opening one. Following a baseline survey, we organised practical information sessions for all the participants. We showed them how to deposit and withdraw, and demonstrated the importance of a fingerprint recognition tool that protects their account. From February till May 2014, we hired a centrally located room in each village, where we interviewed the participants on a weekly basis for a total of 7 to 13 weeks. We gathered detailed information on the evolution of the various earnings and expenditures of the household members over the past 7 days. The respondents were paid 150 rupees for each interview, and randomly allocated to being paid on the account (treated) or in cash (control). They were free to deposit or withdraw the amount they want, the transaction costs were negligible, and the bank was located at their doorstep. The only cost was the couple of minutes it takes to perform a transaction.

This simple change in the payment method led to a tremendous difference in savings and consumption patterns. Our results can be summarised as follows.

  • First, we find that being paid on the account instead of in cash increases the account balance by around 110% (or almost 420 rupees) within three months of weekly payments.
  • Second, the effects are long lasting; five months after the last weekly payment, the balance of the treated is still twice the one of the control.
  • Third, the villagers that were paid in cash do not save more in other assets, such as cash at home. As a result, the treatment had a net positive impact on the respondent’s total savings.
  • Fourth, the villagers who were paid in cash increase expenditures on regular consumption, such as rice, vegetables, fuels, and soap with about 402 rupees, an increase that is remarkably similar to the increase in the savings of the villagers paid on the account.

Finally, the effects are uniform across different sub-samples. The treatment has similar effects on men and women, and on old and new account holders, two characteristics on which we had stratified our sample.

Moving back to cash payments ends savings

Our results provide evidence that account use and savings are easily enhanced by moving from cash to account based payments for a broad segment of the population. An important remaining question is whether individuals who are paid on the account develop the habit to save on that account. We tested this by twisting the original design. After a break of seven weeks, we did interviews for four extra weeks, but compensated everyone in cash. These extra weeks were not announced and could not have been anticipated by the respondents. We explicitly told them that the use of the accounts is the same, but that they have to make deposits themselves if they want to save on the account. During these weeks, the change in the account balance is the same for both groups. Furthermore, the treated and control no longer differ in terms of consumption patterns.

We graphically represent the evolution of the account balance in Figure 1 below. The control villagers are always paid in cash, while the treated respondents were paid on the account during phase 1, and in cash during phase 2. The balance of the people who were paid on the account increases much quicker than the one of the respondents who were paid in cash during the first 13 weeks. From weeks 14 to 21, they did not receive payments and the balances decrease in both groups. The decline is sharper in the treated group, and is consistent with consumption smoothing. During phase 2, the account balance of the treated remains twice as high as the balance of the control individuals, but – even though the respondents receive the exact same income during phase 2 as during phase 1 – we no longer observe a differential increase in the savings of the treated. The observed difference was created during the weeks in which the treated were paid on the account.

Figure 1.

vandewalle fig1 8 may

These findings are relevant for the design of financial inclusion policies. Existing studies show that the demand for bank accounts is high, but not sufficient to trigger an active use. We draw attention to the next step. Once private or public transfers are made on the account – instead of in cash – the account becomes truly active and savings are stimulated.

This article is published in collaboration with Vox EU. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Vincent Somville is a Senior Researcher, Chr. Michelsen Institute. Lore Vandewalle is an Assistant Professor of Economics, Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies.

Image: A customer withdraws 500 Estonian kroon ($40) from an ATM in Tallinn. REUTERS/Ints Kalnins 

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Financial and Monetary SystemsEconomic Growth
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

How fintech innovation can unlock Africa’s gaming revolution

Lucy Hoffman

April 24, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum