Financial and Monetary Systems

5 reasons the Fed shouldn’t raise rates

Lawrence H. Summers
President Emeritus, Harvard Kennedy School of Government
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Financial and Monetary Systems?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how United States is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

United States

Two weeks ago, I argued that a Federal Reserve decision to raise rates in September would be a serious mistake. As I wrote my column, the market was assigning a 50 percent chance to a rate hike. The current chance is 34 percent. Having followed the debate among economists, Fed governors and bank presidents, I believe the case against a rate increase has become somewhat more compelling than it looked even two weeks ago.

Five points are salient.

First, markets have already done the work of tightening. The U.S. stock market is worth $700 billion less than it was two weeks ago, while credit spreads have widened noticeably. Financial conditions, as measured by Goldman Sachs or the Chicago Fed index, have tightened in the last two weeks by the impact equivalent of more than a .25-percentage-point increase in interest rates. So even if resisting inflation required a .25-percentage-point tightening as of two weeks ago, this is no longer the case.

The figure below makes an additional, crucial point. As a consequence of the various factors promoting secular stagnation through increased saving and reduced investment, any given level of financial support for growth requires much lower real federal funds rates than was once the case. This table shows that even though the fed funds rate is very low (negative one and a half percent after adjusting for inflation), financial conditions are helping the economy less, providing less stimulus, than in previous years when interest rates were much higher.

Second, the data flow suggests a slowing in the U.S. and global economies and reduced inflationary pressures. Employment growth appears to have slowed down, commodity prices have fallen further, and the general data flow has been on the soft side. Comprehensive measures of data surprises, such as the Bloomberg Economic Surprise Index, bear out this impression, and the Atlanta Fed’s GDP Now model is currently predicting only 1.5 percent growthin the third quarter.

Third, the case for concern about inflation breaking out is very weak. Market-based expectations suggest that inflation over the next decade on the Fed’s preferred measure – core personal consumption expenditures (PCEs), which exclude energy and food prices – is near record lows and well below 2 percent, the Fed’s long-run target for inflation. The observation that five-year inflation, five years from now, is expected to be below target calls into question arguments that current low inflation is somehow transitory.

The recent analysis presented by Fed Vice Chair Stanley Fischer in Jackson Hole asserting to the contrary – suggesting that the strong U.S. dollar has restrained underlying inflation pressures by reducing the cost of imports – relies on assumptions about exchange rates and inflation. When actual empirical estimates are used, his conclusions are substantially weakened. Indeed, as the figure below shows, there is no correlation of late between deceleration in inflation and import share looking across PCE components.

150910- US interest rates Larry Summers Wonk Blog

As regards inflation, it bears emphasis that (i) we have some room for inflation acceleration, (ii) prices are now fully 2 percent below a 2 percent inflation path taking off from 2010, and (iii) the Phillips curve, which promises to describe the relationship between unemployment and inflation, is so unstable that it provides little basis for predicting inflation acceleration. To take just two examples, unemployment among college graduates is 2.5 percent, yet there is no evidence that their wages are accelerating. And unemployment in Nebraska has been below 4 percent for the last three years, but growth in average hourly earnings has been basically constant at the national-average level.

Fourth, arguments of the “one and done” variety or arguments that the Fed can safely raise rates by .25 percentage points as long as it’s clear that there is no commitment to a series of hikes are specious. If, as some suggest, a .25-percentage-point increase won’t affect the economy much at all, what is the case for an increase? And when the same people argue that a .25-percentage-point hike will have little impact and that it is vital to get off the zero rate floor, my head spins a bit.

In a highly uncertain world, the Fed cannot be both data dependent and predictable with respect to its future actions. Much better that it stick with data dependence than that it put its credibility at risk by seeking to mitigate a current rash action by trying to reassure with respect to future steps.

I understand the argument that zero rates are a sign of pathology, and the economy is no longer diseased, so policymakers have to increase rates. The problem is that the case for hitting the brakes in an economy with sub-target inflation, employment and output is not there — regardless of whether the brakes are going to be pressed hard or softly, singly or multiple times.

From the Depression to the Vietnam War to the Iraq war to the euro crisis, we surely should learn that policymakers who elevate credibility over responding to clear realities make grave errors. The best way the Fed can maintain and enhance its credibility is to support a fully employed American economy achieving its inflation target with stable financial conditions. The greatest damage it could do to its credibility would be to embrace central-banking shibboleth disconnected from current economic reality.

Fifth, I believe that conventional wisdom substantially underestimates the risks in the current moment. It bears emphasis that not a single postwar recession was predicted a year in advance by the Fed, the federal government, the International Monetary Fund or a consensus of forecasters. Most were not recognized until long after they started. And if history teaches anything, it is that financial interconnections are pervasive and not apparent until it’s too late. Russia’s 1998 default, problems in subprime lending, and the Asian financial crisis were all moments when financial dislocations had far more pervasive effects than was generally expected.

We know that China is in its most uncertain state since it began economic reform in 1979 and may well be experiencing a larger volume of capital flight than any economy in history. We know that the central banks of Japan and Europe are likely to have to double down in the months ahead on already extraordinary quantitative easing. We know that American households, firms and markets are processing what appears to a kind of “reverse 1990s” moment of sharply decelerating productivity growth. We know that liquidity conditions in markets have worsened, and there is at least some reason to believe that “positive feedback” trading strategies, where investors sell when prices go down, may well have become increasingly important. We know the current U.S. recovery is in its seventh year and that confidence in public institutions is at a low ebb.

More likely than not, these fears are overblown, and 2015 and 2016 will not go down in financial history. If so, and the Fed does not act, inflation will start to accelerate, volatility will subside, and policy can step in. Regret may come in the form of inflation a few tens of a percentage point too high or a bit of euphoric relief in markets. If, on the other hand, some portion of these fears are warranted and the Fed tips toward tightening, it risks catastrophic error.

Now is the time for the Fed to do what is often hardest for policymakers. Stand still.

This article is published in collaboration with Wonk Blog. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Lawrence H. Summers, the Charles W. Eliot university professor at Harvard, is a former treasury secretary and director of the National Economic Council in the White House. 

Image: The United States Federal Reserve Board building is shown in Washington October 28, 2014. REUTERS/Gary Cameron 

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Financial and Monetary SystemsEconomic Growth
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

How fintech innovation can unlock Africa’s gaming revolution

Lucy Hoffman

April 24, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum