Trade and Investment

This is how much the end of Schengen could cost Europe

Euro and U.S. dollar banknotes are seen in this picture illustration taken in Prague January 23, 2013. The euro hit an 11-month high and shares rose January 25, 2013 on signs the region's financial system was returning to health and the outlook for Germany, the currency bloc's biggest economy, brightened. Sentiment was lifted when the European Central Bank said 278 banks in the region would repay a total of 137 billion euros in emergency three-year loans provided just over year ago to avoid a major credit crunch as the debt crisis worsened. Picture taken January 23.

New research outlines the economic benefits of Schengen, and the potential costs should the agreement collapse. Image: REUTERS/David W Cerny

Jasmin Gröschl
Economist, IFO Center for International Economics
Thomas Steinwachs
Junior Economist and Doctoral Student, Ifo Center for International Economics
Gabriel Felbermayr
Director, Ifo Center for International Economics, Ifo Institute for Economic Research in Munich
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Trade and Investment?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Trade and Investment is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Trade and Investment

Time and again, the Eurobarometer surveys show that a vast majority of Europeans view the free movement of people, goods and services across borders as the most important achievement of the EU. This is probably because the removal of identity checks at internal EU borders through the Schengen Agreement is a very tangible advantage of European integration. However, since autumn 2015, several EU member states have reintroduced border controls in a reaction to the refugee crisis and terrorist attacks.

Schengen has facilitated travel within Europe. However, one motivation for Schengen always has been the promotion of cross-border trade in goods and services (Ademmer et al. 2015). The idea is that the removal of border waiting times reduces trade costs, thereby stimulating cross border exchange and the mobility of service providers and consumers. This should yield higher welfare for EU citizens. The reintroduction of controls puts these gains at risk.

In this contribution, we ask:

-Has Schengen really promoted trade in goods and services, and if yes, by how much?

-Which EU member states benefit the most from it?

-What are the trade and welfare costs of the border controls currently notified to the Commission?

-And, what if the border controls were reinstated at all internal borders?

To answer these questions, we draw on our recent research (Felbermayr et al 2016). More precisely, we apply an econometric gravity model to historical data (1995-2011) to measure the trade effects of the Schengen Agreement. We then turn to a simple counterfactual analysis based on the most recent data in which we impose border controls on certain intra-EU borders.

Setup

The Schengen Agreement, first enforced in 1995 amongst six countries (BENELUX, France, Germany, Italy), has grown over time and today includes about 400 million citizens in 26 countries (see Figure 1). Not all EU members are part of Schengen, but some non-EU countries are. All EZ countries are Schengen members, but they ratified the agreement at different times. From an econometric point of view, the often bemoaned variable geometry of Europe is an advantage. It allows us to use panel econometrics to disentangle the different effects of the EU, the Eurozone, and Schengen membership and of other trade agreements (e.g. EFTA, EEA, or pre-accession treaties).

Figure 1. Overview of the Schengen Area as of April 2016

The status of the Schengen Area, showing member countries and potential members.
Image: VOX EU

The trade effects of the Schengen Agreement have an obvious spatial dimension. A land-borne trade flow between two countries in Europe may cross only one internal border (e.g. France to Germany) or up to eight of them (e.g. Portugal to Finland). Hence, Schengen membership treats country pairs in a heterogeneous way. This feature is ignored in the small existing literature (e.g. Davis and Gift 2013). What is more, Schengen outsiders such as the UK or Turkey can also benefit from the agreement to the extent that their trade flows transit through Schengen space. To deal with this, we combine GIS data with information from Google Maps to count the number of Schengen borders crossed by truck (and ferry) along the shortest road distance between trading country pairs. This count variable is our measure of interest.

Schengen membership has promoted trade in goods and services...

We carried out a gravity regression analysis on data from the World Input-Output Data (WIOD) project (Felbermayr et al. 2016). This allows the separation of services trade from goods trade, and international from intra-national trade flows. The data are available for 40 countries (including 27 EU members) and have been described by Escaith and Timmer (2012). The econometric model follows the recommendations in Head and Mayer (2015). Figure 2 shows that – conditional on membership in the EU, in the Eurozone, or in any other regional trade agreement (and conditional on the usual gravity controls and a host of pair and time fixed effects) – the removal of controls on one internal border is equivalent to a reduction of a tariff by 0.7 percentage points. This effect is precisely estimated for goods, but less so for services. Numerous robustness checks in our paper corroborate this general finding.

EU membership is much more important than Schengen, though. The cumulated effects of the customs union and the single market are equivalent to a tariff reduction of almost 18 percentage points for goods and 7 percentage points for services. Other RTAs and the euro also yield larger trade cost reductions.

Figure 2. Average treatment effects of European integration policies, expressed as reductions of ad valorem tariff equivalents (%)

Ad valorem tariff equivalents
Image: VOX EU

We find these effects plausible. Evidence from the US-Canadian border or from current external Schengen borders suggest waiting times that average 20 minutes (Ifo 2016). Bottom-up estimates yield much smaller costs, but are less comprehensive by construction. The estimates suggest that the tariff equivalents of 3% assumed in recent policy work (Aussilloux and Le Hir 2016, Böhmer et al. 2016) may be too high.

When a trade route involves several internal borders, the cost savings accumulate – a truck from Italy to Germany crosses two internal borders so that Schengen is equivalent to a trade cost saving of about 1.4%; a truck from Portugal to Poland crosses four internal borders so that Schengen saves about 2.8%. However, more than 80% of intracontinental trade in Europe crosses only one or two internal borders (see Figure 3).

Figure 3. Total EU-28 trade in billion euros along the number of Schengen borders crossed, 2011

EU exports and imports in billions of Euros along Schengen borders.
Image: VOX EU

...but some countries benefit more from Schengen than others

Clearly, different countries will be affected differently by Schengen, simply because geography, history, and specialisation patterns imply that countries are heterogeneous with respect to the average number of internal borders that trade flows cross. In other words, every country has its own breakdown analogous to Figure 3.

Figure 4 shows average cost savings from Schengen for various countries. For example, across all intracontinental trade flows of Austria, Schengen amounts to trade cost savings of 0.81% for goods and 0.75% for services. Thus, the country occupies a middle ground. For countries at the periphery such as Portugal or Finland, Schengen matters more. It is equivalent to trade cost savings for goods of 1.28% and 1.59%, respectively. In contrast, Ireland, whose main trade partners are the Schengen outsiders UK and US, the savings amount to only 0.42%. Figure 4 also shows that Schengen outsiders such as Russia or Turkey benefit from the removal of internal border controls, too.

Figure 4. Average trade costs savings from Schengen for various countries’ intracontinental trade, 2011

The average trade cost savings from Schengen for various countries.
Image: VOX EU

The costs of border controls along refugee routes: An approximation

As a reaction to the massive inflow of refugees, in September 2015, Germany introduced border controls at the Austrian border; in November, Sweden started ID checks at the Öresund Bridge; and Austria reinstated controls at its border with Slovenia and Italy. The terrorist attacks in Paris in November 2015 led to border controls at French borders. Considering all border controls reported to the EU under Article 23 et seq. of the Schengen Borders Code since summer 2015, and applying our estimates, we find that overall goods and services trade of EU-28 countries declines, on average, by 1.3% compared to the status quo in 2011; this corresponds to an annual decline in trade volumes of €70.19 billion. Using a trade elasticity of 5 in the welfare formula of Arkolakis et al. (2012), this effect lowers aggregate real GDP of EU28 members by €12.51 billion, or 0.10% of GDP. However, there is a great degree of heterogeneity, as countries differ with respect to the importance of trade with partners in the southeast of Europe (see Figure 5).

The costs of a complete Schengen collapse

What if identity checks were to be reinstated at all internal borders? In this scenario, our calculations suggest that overall goods and services trade of EU28 countries declines, on average, by 4.2%, relative to the status quo in 2011; this corresponds to an annual decline in trade volumes of €221.34 billion compared to a counterfactual situation without any border controls imposed within the Schengen area. The aggregate real GDP of EU28 members would fall by 0.31%; that is, by €39.3 billion.

Figure 5. Welfare effects for selected countries (% of real GDP per capita)

Welfare effects for selected countries
Image: VOX EU

Again, our analysis suggests that peripheral and/or small countries are much more strongly affected than central and/or large ones. Interestingly, Schengen outsiders such as Turkey and the UK would feel the effect, too.

References

Ademmer, E, T Barsbai, M Lücke and T Stöhr (2015) “30 Years of Schengen, internal blessing, external curse?“, Kiel Policy Brief 88.

Arkolakis, C, A Costinot and A Rodríguez-Clare (2012) “New trade models, same old gains?”,American Economic Review, 102(1): 94-130.

Aussilloux, V and B Le Hir (2016) “The economic costs of rolling back Schengen”, France Stratégie Policy Brief.

Böhmer, M, J Limbers, A Pivac and H Weinelt (2016) “Departure from the Schengen Agreement – Macroeconomic impacts of Germany and the countries of the European Union”, GED Study on behalf of Bertelsmann Foundation, Prognos AG.

Davis, D and T Gift (2014) “The positive effects of the Schengen Agreement on European trade”,World Economy, 37(11): 1541-1557.

Escaith, H and M Timmer (2012) “Global value chains, trade, jobs, and environment: The new WIOD database”, VoxEU.org, 13 May 2012.

Felbermayr, G, J Gröschl and T Steinwachs (2016) “The trade effects of border controls: Evidence from the European Schengen Agreement”, Ifo Working Paper No. 213.

Head, K and T Mayer (2015) “Gravity equations, workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook”, in G Gopinath, E Helpman and K Rogoff (eds), Handbook of International Economics, 4th edition, Amsterdam: Elsevir, 131-195.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Trade and InvestmentEuropean Union
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

International trade: What you need to know this month

Mariam Soumaré

March 28, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum